Statements (52)
Predicate | Object |
---|---|
gptkbp:instanceOf |
gptkb:economic_policy
|
gptkbp:analyzes |
reaction functions
|
gptkbp:appliesTo |
oligopoly
|
gptkbp:assumes |
imperfect competition
barriers to entry profit maximization complete information static game homogeneous products no collusion sequential moves rational players simultaneous price setting not allowed |
gptkbp:contrastsWith |
gptkb:Cournot_competition
gptkb:Bertrand_competition |
gptkbp:describes |
strategic interaction between firms
|
gptkbp:example |
automobile industry
energy markets telecommunications industry airline industry |
gptkbp:extendsTo |
dynamic games
multiple firms differentiated products |
gptkbp:features |
leader-follower dynamic
|
gptkbp:field |
microeconomics
industrial organization |
gptkbp:firstDescribed |
1934
|
gptkbp:followerAdvantage |
reacts to leader's choice
|
gptkbp:followerFirm |
chooses output after leader
|
gptkbp:form |
backward induction
|
gptkbp:generalizes |
Cournot model
|
https://www.w3.org/2000/01/rdf-schema#label |
Stackelberg competition
|
gptkbp:influenced |
modern industrial organization theory
|
gptkbp:leaderAdvantage |
first-mover advantage
|
gptkbp:leaderFirm |
chooses output first
|
gptkbp:limitation |
assumes perfect information
does not account for collusion |
gptkbp:namedAfter |
Heinrich Freiherr von Stackelberg
|
gptkbp:relatedTo |
game theory
market structure duopoly |
gptkbp:result |
leader earns higher profit than follower
market price lower than Cournot equilibrium total output higher than Cournot equilibrium |
gptkbp:solvedBy |
subgame perfect Nash equilibrium
|
gptkbp:studiedIn |
economics textbooks
|
gptkbp:usedFor |
analyzing market power
studying firm strategy |
gptkbp:bfsParent |
gptkb:Cournot_competition
gptkb:Bertrand_competition gptkb:Subgame_Perfect_Equilibrium |
gptkbp:bfsLayer |
7
|